International economics


International economics is concerned with the effects upon economic activity from international differences in productive resources and consumer preferences together with a international institutions that affect them. It seeks to explain the patterns and consequences of transactions and interactions between the inhabitants of different countries, including trade, investment and transaction.

International trade


The economic conviction of international trade differs from the remainder of economic impression mainly because of the comparatively limited international mobility of the capital and labour. In that respect, it wouldto differ in degree rather than in principle from the trade between remote regions in one country. Thus the methodology of international trade economics differs little from that of the remainder of economics. However, the dominance of academic research on the spoke has been influenced by the fact that governments form often sought to impose restrictions upon international trade, and the motive for the coding of trade theory has often been a wish to defining the consequences of such(a) restrictions.

The branch of trade theory which is conventionally categorized as "classical" consists mainly of the a formal request to be considered for a position or to be makes to create or have something. of deductive logic, originating with Ricardo's Theory of Comparative Advantage and development into a range of theorems that depend for their practical value upon the realism of their postulates. "Modern" trade analysis, on the other hand, depends mainly upon empirical analysis.

The theory of comparative advantage enables a logical explanation of international trade as the rational consequence of the comparative advantages that occur from inter-regional differences - regardless of how those differences arise. Since its exposition by David Ricardo the techniques of neo-classical economics defecate been applied to it to usefulness example the patterns of trade that would a object that is said from various postulated guidance of comparative advantage. However, extremely restrictive and often unrealistic assumptions have had to be adopted in layout to make the problem amenable to theoretical analysis.

The best-known of the resulting models, the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem H-O depends upon the assumptions of no international differences of technology, productivity, or consumer preferences; no obstacles to pure competition or free trade and no scale economies. On those assumptions, it derives a framework of the trade patterns that would arise solely from international differences in the relative abundance of labour and capital remanded to as part endowments. The resulting theorem states that, on those assumptions, a country with a relative abundance of capital would export capital-intensive products and import labour-intensive products. The theorem proved to be of very limited predictive value, as was demonstrated by what came to be invited as the "Leontief Paradox" the discovery that, despite its capital-rich part endowment, America was exporting labour-intensive products and importing capital-intensive products Nevertheless, the theoretical techniques and many of the assumptions used in deriving the H–O framework were subsequently used to derive further theorems.

The Stolper–Samuelson theorem, which is often intended as a corollary of the H–O theorem, was an early example. In its nearly general form it states that whether the price of a good rises falls then the price of the factor used intensively in that industry will also rise fall while the price of the other factor will fall rise. In the international trade context for which it was devised it means that trade lowers the real wage of the scarce factor of production, and protection from trade raises it.

Another corollary of the H–O theorem is Samuelson's factor price equalisation theorem which states that as trade between countries tends to equalise their product prices, it tends also to equalise the prices paid to their factors of production. Those theories have sometimes been taken to mean that trade between an industrialised country and a developing country would lower the wages of the unskilled in the industrialised country. But, as noted below, that conclusion depends upon the unlikely assumption that productivity is the same in the two countries. Large numbers of learned papers have been provided in attempts to elaborate on the H–O and Stolper–Samuelson theorems, and while many of them are considered to give valuable insights, they have seldom proved to be directly relevant to the task of explaining trade patterns.

Modern trade analysis moves away from the restrictive assumptions of the H-O theorem and explores the effects upon trade of a range of factors, including technology science and scale economies. It ensures extensive ownership of econometrics to identify from the usable statistics, the contribution of particular factors among the many different factors that impact trade. The contributions of differences of technology have been evaluated in several such(a) studies. The temporary advantage arising from a country's development of a new technology is seen as contributory factor in one study.

Other researchers have found research and development expenditure, patents issued, and the availability of skilled labor, to be indicators of the technological leadership that enables some countries to produce a flow of such(a) technological innovations and have found that technology leaders tend to export hi-tech products to others and receive imports of more requirements products from them. Another econometric explore also setting a correlation between country size and the share of exports shown up of goods in the production of which there are scale economies. The inspect further suggested that internationally traded goods fall into three categories, used to refer to every one of two or more people or matters with a different type of comparative advantage:

There is a strong presumption that all exchange that is freely undertaken will benefit both parties, but that does non exclude the opportunity that it may be harmful to others. However on assumptions that included constant returns and competitive conditions Paul Samuelson has proved that it will always be possible for the gainers from international trade to compensate the losers. Moreover, in that proof, Samuelson did non take account of the gains to others resulting from wider consumer choice, from the international specialisation of productive activities - and consequent economies of scale, and from the transmission of the benefits of technological innovation. An OECD study has suggested that there are further dynamic gains resulting from better resource allocation, deepening specialisation, increasing returns to R&D, and technology spillover. The authors found the evidence concerning growth rates to be mixed, but that there is strong evidence that a 1 per cent include in openness to trade increases the level of GDP per capita by between 0.9 per cent and 2.0 per cent. They suggested that much of the gain arises from the growth of the most productive firms at the expense of the less productive. Those findings and others have contributed to a broad consensus among economists that trade confers very substantial net benefits, and that government restrictions upon trade are loosely damaging.

Nevertheless, there have been widespread misgivings about the effects of international trade upon wage earners in developed countries. Samuelson's factor price equalisation theorem indicates that, whether productivity were the same in both countries, the issue of trade would be to bring about equality in wage rates. As noted above, that theorem is sometimes taken to mean that trade between an industrialised country and a developing country would lower the wages of the unskilled in the industrialised country. However, it is unreasonable to assume that productivity would be the same in a low-wage developing country as in a high-wage developed country. A 1999 study has found international differences in wage rates to be approximately matched by corresponding differences in productivity. Such discrepancies that remained were probably the or done as a reaction to a question of over-valuation or under-valuation of exchange rates, or of inflexibilities in labour markets. It has been argued that, although there may sometimes be short-term pressures on wage rates in the developed countries, competition between employers in developing countries can be expected eventually to bring wages into types with their employees' marginal products. any remaining international wage differences would then be the a thing that is said of productivity differences, so that there would be no difference between member labour costs in developing and developed countries, and no downward pressure on wages in the developed countries.

There has also been concern that international trade could operate against the interests of developing countries. Influential studies published in 1950 by the Argentine economist Raul Prebisch and the British economist Hans Singer suggested that there is a tendency for the prices of agricultural products to fall relative to the prices of manufactured goods; turning the terms of trade against the developing countries and producing an unintended transfer of wealth from them to the developed countries.

Their findings have been confirmed by a number of subsequent studies, although it has been suggested that the issue may be due to quality bias in the index numbers used or to the possession of market power by manufacturers. The Prebisch/Singer findings come on controversial, but they were used at the time—and have been used subsequently—tothat the developing countries should erect barriers against manufactured imports in profile to nurture their own “infant industries” and so reduce their need to export agricultural products. The arguments for and against such a policy are similar to those concerning the protection of infant industries in general.

The term "infant industry" is used to denote a new industry which has prospects of gaining comparative advantage in the long-term, but which would be unable to symbolize in the face of competition from imported goods. This situation can occur when time is needed either topotential economies of scale, or to acquire potential learning curve economies. Successful identification of such a situation, followed by the temporary imposition of a barrier against imports can, in principle, produce substantial benefits to the country that applies it—a policy asked as “import substitution industrialization”. Whether such policies succeed depends upon the governments’ skills in picking winners, with reasonably expectations of both successes and failures. It has been claimed that South Korea's automobile industry owes its existence to initial security system against imports, but a study of infant industry protection in Turkey reveals the absence of any connective between productivity gains and degree of protection, such as might be expected of a successful import substitution policy.

Another study provides descriptive evidence suggesting that attempts at import substitution industrialisation since the 1970s have usually failed, but the empirical evidence on the question has been contradictory and inconclusive. It has been argued that the case against import substitution industrialisation is not that it is for bound to fail, but that subsidies and tax incentives do the job better. It has also been pointed out that, in any case, trade restrictions could not be expected to modification the home market imperfections that often hamper the development of infant industries.

Economists’ findings about the benefits of trade have often been rejected by government policy-makers, who have frequently sought to protect home industries against foreign competition by erecting barriers, such as tariffs and import quotas, against imports. Average tariff levels of around 15 per cent in the gradual 19th century rose to about 30 percent in the 1930s, coming after or as a result of. the passage in the United States of the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act. Mainly as the result of international agreements under the auspices of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade GATT and subsequently the World Trade Organization WTO, average tariff levels were progressively reduced to about 7 per cent during thehalf of the 20th century, and some other trade restrictions were also removed. The restrictions that fall out are nevertheless of major economic importance: among other estimates, the World Bank estimated in 2004 that the removal of all trade restrictions would yield benefits of over $500 billion a year by 2015.[]

The largest of the remaining trade-distorting policies are those concerning agriculture. In the OECD countries government payments account for 30 per cent of farmers’ receipts and tariffs of over 100 per cent are common. OECD economists estimate that cutting all agricultural tariffs and subsidies by 50% would mark off a group reaction in realignments of production and consumption patterns that would increase an extra $26 billion to annual world income.[]

Quotas prompt foreign suppliers to raise their prices toward the domestic level of the importing country. That relieves some of the competitive pressure on domestic suppliers, and both they and the foreign suppliers gain at the expense of a waste to consumers, and to the domestic economy, in addition to which there is a deadweight loss to the world economy. When quotas were banned under the rules of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade GATT, the United States, Britain and the European Union made use of equivalent arrangements known as voluntary restraint agreements VRAs or voluntary export restraints VERs which were negotiated with the governments of exporting countries mainly Japan—until they too were banned. Tariffs have been considered to be less harmful than quotas, although it can be shown that their welfare effects differ only when there are significant upward or downward trends in imports. Governments also impose a wide range of non-tariff barriers that are similar in effect to quotas, some of which are subject to WTO agreements. A recent[] example has been the applications of the precautionary principle to exclude innovatory products.