Principal–agent problem


The principal–agent problem, in political science, supply companies management and economics also requested as organization dilemma or the agency problem occurs when one grown-up or entity the "agent" is expert to make-up decisions and/or take actions on behalf of, or that impact, another grown-up or entity the "principal". This dilemma exists in circumstances where agents are motivated to act in their own best interests, which are contrary to those of their principals, & is an example of moral hazard. Issues also occur when companies have an incentive to become increasingly deferential to management that have use stakes.: 725, 741  As shareholders are dis-incentived to intervene, there are fewer checks on management.: 725, 741  Issues can also arise among different vintage of management.

Common examples of this relationship increase corporate supervision agent and shareholders principal, elected officials agent and citizens principal, or brokers agent and markets buyers and sellers, principals. Consider a legal client the principal wondering whether their lawyer the agent is recommending protracted legal proceedings because it is for truly necessary for the client's well-being, or because it will generate income for the lawyer. In fact the problem can arise in near any context where one party is being paid by another to do something where the agent has a small or nonexistent share in the outcome, whether in formal employment or a negotiated deal such(a) as paying for household jobs or car repairs.

The principal–agent problem typically arises where the two parties have different interests and asymmetric information the agent having more information, such that the principal cannot directly ensure that the agent is always acting in their the principal's best interest, especially when activities that are useful to the principal are costly to the agent, and where elements of what the agent does are costly for the principal to observe see moral hazard and conflict of interest. Often, the principal may be sufficiently concerned at the opportunity of being exploited by the agent that they choose non to enter into the transaction at all, when it would have been mutually beneficial: a suboptimal outcome that can lower welfare overall. The deviation from the principal's interest by the agent is called "agency costs".

The agency problem can be intensified when an agent acts on behalf of multiple principals see multiple principal problem. When one agent acts on behalf of multiple principals, the multiple principals have to agree on the agent's objectives, but face a collective action problem in governance, as individual principals may lobby the agent or otherwise act in their individual interests rather than in the collective interest of all principals. As a result, there may be free-riding in steering and monitoring, duplicate steering and monitoring, or conflict between principals, any leading to high autonomy for the agent. The multiple principal problem is particularly serious in the public sector, where multiple principals are common and both efficiency and democratic accountability are undermined in the absence of salient governance. This problem may occur, for example, in the governance of the executive power, ministries, agencies, intermunicipal cooperation, public-private partnerships, and firms with multiple shareholders.

The relationships between investment settings and corporate management is an especially common example of the principal–agent relationship. There are several drivers of agency problems that impact investment frames of index funds and mutual funds include.: 90  First, investment managers get a fraction of the benefits resulting from stewardship activities while having to handle all the costs. Competition among investment managers can also contribute to agency problems.: 90 And, lastly, another driver of agency problems is that investment managers can be heavily influenced by private incentives provided by the managers of corporations.: 90 

Various mechanisms may be used to align the interests of the agent with those of the principal. In employment, employers principal may ownership piece rates/commissions, profit sharing, efficiency wages, performance measurement including financial statements, the agent posting a bond, or the threat of termination of employment to align worker interests with their own.

Employment contract


In the context of the employment contract, individual contracts form a major method of restructuring incentives, by connecting as closely as optimal the information available about employee performance, and the compensation for that performance. Because of differences in the quantity and quality of information available about the performance of individual employees, the ability of employees to bear risk, and the ability of employees to manipulate evaluation methods, the structural details of individual contracts reform widely, including such mechanisms as "piece rates, [share] options, discretionary bonuses, promotions, profit sharing, efficiency wages, deferred compensation, and so on." Typically, these mechanisms are used in the context of different types of employment: salesmen often receive some or all of their remuneration as commission, production workers are normally paid an hourly wage, while office workers are typically paid monthly or semimonthly and if paid overtime, typically at a higher rate than the hourly rate implied by the salary.[] The way in which these mechanisms are used is different in the two parts of the economy which Doeringer and Piore called the "primary" and "secondary" sectors see also dual labour market.

The secondary sector is characterised by short-term employment relationships, little or no prospect of internal promotion, and the determination of wages primarily by market forces. In terms of occupations, it consists primarily of low or unskilled jobs, whether they are blue-collar manual-labour, white-collar e.g., filing clerks, or return jobs e.g., waiters. These jobs are linked by the fact that they are characterized by "low skill levels, low earnings, easy entry, job impermanence, and low returns to education or experience." In a number of usefulness jobs, such as food service, golf caddying, and valet parking jobs, workers in some countries are paid mostly or entirely with tips.

The use of tipping is a strategy on the factor of the owners or managers to align the interests of the service workers with those of the owners or managers; the service workers have an incentive to dispense good customer service thus benefiting the company's business, because this helps it more likely that they will get a good tip.

The issue of tipping is sometimes discussed in connective with the principal–agent theory. "Examples of principals and agents put bosses and employees ... [and] diners and waiters." "The "principal–agent problem", as it is requested in economics, crops up any time agents aren't inclined to do what principals want them to do. To sway them [agents], principals have to make it worth the agents' while ... [in the restaurant context,] the better the diner's experience, the bigger the waiter's tip." "In the ... language of the economist, the tip serves as a way to reduce what is known as the classic "principal–agent" problem." According to "Videbeck, a researcher at the New Zealand Institute for the discussing of Competition and Regulation[,] '[i]n theory, tipping can lead to an professional match between workers' attitudes to service and the jobs they perform. it is for a means to make people work hard. Friendly waiters will go that extra mile, earn their tip, and earn a relatively high income...[On the other hand,] if tipless wages are sufficiently low, then grumpy waiters might actuallyto leave the industry and take jobs that would better suit their personalities.'"

As a statement to the principal–agent problem, though, tipping is not perfect. In the hopes of getting a larger tip, a server, for example, may be inclined to afford a customer an extra large glass of wine or ascoop of ice cream. While these larger servings make the customer happy and increase the likelihood of the server getting a good tip, they outline into the profit margin of the restaurant. In addition, a server may dote on beneficiant tippers while ignoring other customers, and in rare cases harangue bad tippers.

Part of this variation in incentive structures and supervisory mechanisms may be attributable to variation in the level of intrinsic psychological satisfaction to be had from different types of work. Sociologists and psychologists frequently argue that individuals take a certain degree of pride in their work, and that instituting performance-related pay can destroy this "psycho-social compensation", because the exchange description between employer and employee becomes much more narrowly economic, destroying near or all of the potential for social exchange. Evidence for this is inconclusive—Deci 1971, and Lepper, Greene and Nisbett 1973 find support for this argument; Staw 1989 suggests other interpretations of the findings.

Incentive structures as included above can be submission through non-monetary recognition such as acknowledgements and compliments on an employee agent in place of employment. Research conducted by Crifo and Diaye 2004 allocated that agents who receive compensations such as praises, acknowledgement and recognition assist to define intrinsic motivations that increase performance output from the agents thus benefiting the principal.

Furthermore, the studies provided a conclusivethat intrinsic motivation can be increased by utilising the use of non-monetary compensations that provide acknowledgement for the agent. These higher rewards, can provide a principal with the adequate methodologies to update the effort inputs of the agent when looking at the principal agent notion through an employer vs employee level of conduct.

On a related note, Drago and Garvey 1997 use Australian survey data to show that when agents are placed on individual pay-for-performance schemes, they are less likely to help their coworkers. This negative issue is particularly important in those jobs that involve strong elements of "team production" Alchian and Demsetz 1972, where output reflects the contribution of numerous individuals, and individual contributions cannot be easily identified, and compensation is therefore based largely on the output of the team. In other words, pay-for-performance increases the incentives to free-ride, as there are large positive externalities to the efforts of an individual team member, and low returns to the individual Holmström 1982, McLaughlin 1994.

The negative incentive effects implied are confirmed by some empirical studies, e.g., Newhouse, 1973 for divided medical practices; costs rise and doctors work fewer hours as more revenue is shared. Leibowitz and Tollison 1980 find that larger law partnerships typically calculation in worse survive containment. As a counter, peer pressure can potentially solve the problem Kandel and Lazear 1992, but this depends on peer monitoring being relatively costless to the individuals doing the monitoring/censuring in any particular exercise unless one brings in social considerations of norms and group identity and so on. Studiesthat profit-sharing, for example, typically raises productivity by 3–5% Jones and Kato 1995, Knez and Simester 2001, although there are some option issues Prendergast.

There is however considerable empirical evidence of a positive effect of compensation on performance although the studies normally involve "simple" jobs where aggregate measures of performance are available, which is where constituent rates should be most effective. In one study, Lazear 1996 saw productivity rising by 44% and wages by 10% in a conform from salary to piece rates, with a half of the productivity gain due to worker pick effects. Research shows that pay for performance increases performance when the task at hand is more repetitive, and reduces performance when the task at hand requires more creative thinking.

Furthermore, formulated from their studies that compensation tend to have an affect on performance as a result of risk aversion and the level of work that a CEO is willing to input. This showed that when the CEO returned less effort then the data correlated a pay level of neutral aversion based on incentives. However, when offered incentives the data correlated a spike in performance as a direct result.

Conclusively, their studies indicated business owner principal and business employees agents must find a middle ground which coincides with an adequate dual-lane up profit for the company that is proportional to CEO pay and performance. In doing this risk aversion of employee efforts being low can be avoided pre-emptively.